home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- <text>
- <title>
- Eastern Europe Goes To Market
- </title>
- <article>
- <hdr>
- Foreign Policy, Spring 1992
- Eastern Europe Goes to Market
- </hdr>
- <body>
- <p>By Mark Kramer, a research fellow at Brown University's Center
- for Foreign Policy Development and a fellow of Harvard
- University's Russian Research Center.
- </p>
- <p> The collapse of communist rule in Eastern Europe in the
- autumn of 1989 brought with it widespread euphoria about the
- prospects for democratic change and economic prosperity. By the
- start of 1992, however, the optimism of 1989 had been
- supplanted by a sense of gloom. This deepening pessimism stemmed
- in part from the resurgence of old political rivalries and
- national conflicts, including the bloody civil war in Yugoslavia
- and the turbulent dissolution of the Soviet Union. As Western
- Europe moved toward greater political and economic integration,
- Eastern Europe faced disintegration and internecine warfare.
- </p>
- <p> Even if these ethnic and political fissures had remained
- submerged, the growing public awareness in Eastern Europe of the
- region's economic plight would have been enough to sustain a
- mood of pessimism. The task of replacing dysfunctional
- state-controlled economies with viable free-market systems would
- have been formidable under the best of circumstances. In
- Eastern Europe, the task has been further complicated by a
- series of external economic shocks and by the lack of clear
- guidance from past experience. Although previous transitions
- from authoritarianism to democracy in Latin America, the
- Iberian countries, and Greece are instructive, the economic and
- political challenges facing Eastern Europe have no ready
- parallel in modern history. The East European countries find
- themselves embarking on a painful and prolonged economic
- transformation without any guarantee that their sacrifices will
- pay off in the end--but with the risk of growing social and
- political unrest.
- </p>
- <p> Official statistics in all the East European countries paint
- a grim picture of the first two years of postcommunist
- transitions, revealing substantial declines in both production
- and living standards. Advocates of a cautious approach to
- reform widely cite these statistics, claiming that the cure of
- "shock therapy" is killing the patient. In reality, the gloomy
- statistics tell only part of the story and, in some respects,
- are highly misleading. The decline in production in each
- country came exclusively in the inefficient state sector, where
- most of what was lost would have had no place in a viable
- free-market economy. Moreover, the production statistics often
- understate the growth and vibrancy of the private sector,
- especially the rise of small-scale entrepreneurs. In Poland, for
- example, some 1.4 million private businesses opened between
- December 1989 and December 1991, and their impact on the economy
- is not always given due weight by statisticians.
- </p>
- <p> Official data showing a precipitous drop in living standards
- and a sharp rise in unemployment are misleading as well. These
- figures do not adequately reflect qualitative improvements in
- peoples lives, such as the disappearance of lines and the
- improved quality of consumer goods and services. Nor do the
- figures take into account money people earn in the private
- sector but fail to report in order to avoid paying taxes. The
- statistics also exaggerate unemployment, counting as unemployed
- those who actually work in the "second," or unofficial,
- economy. The unemployment figures also include people who in
- previous years had been paid wages for work they never
- performed. The disguised unemployment of the communist era has
- now simply been acknowledged.
- </p>
- <p> In short, from an economic standpoint, the initial results of
- the postcommunist transitions are less discouraging than the
- official statistics indicate. From a political standpoint,
- however, the situation is altogether different. In the
- political arena, the actual (or projected) achievements of the
- economic reforms matter less than the public perception of
- those achievements. On this score, there seems little basis for
- optimism. The electoral results in Poland in October 1991, the
- sporadic demonstrations against price increases in Hungary, the
- labor unrest and widening ethnic division in Czechoslovakia,
- and the violent rampages by miners in Romania all bear witness
- to growing popular discontent with the hardships and austerity
- that economic reform requires. The basic question for the East
- European countries over the next few years is whether the
- proponents of economic shock therapy will survive the political
- fallout of their reforms and, if not, what the consequences of a
- gradual approach or even outright failure might be.
- </p>
- <p> Why have the post communist economic transitions in Eastern
- Europe encountered such difficulty, and what might be done to
- improve the situation? Four basic problems have complicated the
- economic transformation of these countries: disruption of
- foreign trade, the ambiguity of property rights, worker
- resistance, and uncertainty about the appropriate sequencing of
- reforms. The first category refers to the external climate for
- reform, whereas the second, third, and fourth categories
- concern internal matters. These four problems are not the only
- ones that the postcommunist states have confronted, but they are
- the most important and they bear, at least indirectly, on all
- other obstacles to the creation of free-market systems.
- </p>
- <p>Trade Shocks
- </p>
- <p>From the late 1940s until 1989, the Soviet Union was by far the
- largest trading partner of all the countries in the region. The
- East European states depended heavily on Soviet supplies of
- energy and raw materials, and many East European firms relied on
- the USSR as their main customer for finished goods. By contrast,
- the USSR, as a largely autarkic state, depended relatively
- little on its imports from Eastern Europe and could easily shift
- its exports of energy and raw materials to the West.
- </p>
- <p> Soon after the upheavals of 1989, Soviet-East European trade
- began to crumble. In 1990 the Soviet Union reduced its
- deliveries of oil and natural gas to Eastern Europe and sought
- to export more to the West for hard currency. Starting in
- January 1991, the USSR and East European countries replaced the
- transferable ruble with the U.S. dollar as the basis for all
- transactions. This change, carried out at Soviet insistence,
- forced the East European and Soviet governments to use world-
- market prices for the goods they traded (including Soviet oil),
- thus ending the artificial pricing system that have long existed
- within the council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON).
- Fittingly enough, COMECON, which had been moribund since late
- 1989, was formally disbanded in June 1991. This shift to
- hard-currency financing not only forced the East Europeans
- states to pay more for Soviet energy supplies and raw
- materials; it also deprived them of vital markets. Because
- Soviet officials and enterprise managers for the most part had
- to use scarce hard currency reserves to pay for East European
- goods, they chose instead to buy what they needed from Western
- suppliers, whose products were of much better quality and only
- slightly more expensive.
- </p>
- <p> The resulting decline in orders for the USSR for East
- European products dealt a sharp blow to East European firms as
- yet unable to compete in Western markets. In the first quarter
- of 1991, Czechoslovak and Hungarian exports to the Soviet Union
- fell by 80 percent, and for the year as a whole they declined by
- nearly the same amount, despite a partial return to barter trade
- in the second half of 1991. The drop in Polish exports to the
- USSR was almost as steep, around 60 percent. The reductions
- particularly hurt pharmaceutical, transportation, cosmetics,
- and food processing industries, leaving them with warehouses of
- unsold goods that were unmarketable in the West.
- </p>
- <p> The growing chaos in the Soviet economy further disrupted
- Soviet-East European trade. By mid-1991, most of the USSR's
- foreign trading responsibilities had devolved to enterprises and
- republic governments, but many of the enterprises did not have
- enough hard currency to pay for imports from both Western and
- Eastern Europe. Consequently, they fell far behind in their
- payments to East European suppliers, and the republic
- governments declined to cover the debts for them. The growing
- unreliability of Soviet enterprises prompted East European
- firms to withhold further supplies to the USSR in the absence
- of bank guarantees, which proved difficult to obtain. This
- credit cutoff prevented additional financial losses for Eastern
- Europe, but it did nothing to bolster export opportunities or
- recover outstanding Soviet debts.
- </p>
- <p> The erosion of trade with the USSR in the first half of 1991
- was the most serious of the external shocks to the East
- European economies, but other developments also contributed to
- the turmoil. Trade with the German Democratic Republic (GDR),
- especially important for Czechoslovakia and Poland, came to an
- end with the reunification of East and West Germany in October
- 1990. Until then, the GDR had provided markets for East European
- agricultural and industrial goods and had been a major supplier
- of scarce industrial components and high-technology products.
- Following German reunification, Czechoslovakia and Poland
- temporarily lost access to these markets and supplies. Further,
- the German-based companies frequently outmaneuvered their East
- European competitors in the quest for Soviet and Western
- markets. Thus, the demise of the GDR cut into Eastern European
- trade from two angles.
- </p>
- <p> In addition to the disruption of trade caused by German
- reunification, trade among all the East European countries
- dropped sharply for several months after the shift to hard-
- currency accounting within COMECON. The same considerations that
- induced Soviet managers to cut back on imports from Eastern
- Europe led the Eastern European countries themselves to forgo
- purchases from one another. To help ease the problem,
- Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland tentatively agreed in
- December 1991 to phase out customs duties, quantitative
- restrictions, and other trade barriers among themselves. The
- agreement, however, could not redeem the damage that had
- already been done, nor could it immediately revive trade among
- the three.
- </p>
- <p> East European trade also suffered as a result of the United
- Nations-sponsored embargo against Iraq. Iraq had been a major
- trading partner for Eastern Europe, and several countries in
- the region lost hundreds and millions of dollars in uncollected
- debt and unfulfilled contracts. The brief surge in oil prices
- during the Persian Gulf crisis further weakened Eastern Europe.
- Although the losses did not cause permanent harm, they were an
- onerous burden during a critical early stage of the economic
- transitions.
- </p>
- <p> If the East European states weather the short-term
- dislocation from these external shocks, the outlook over the
- medium to longer term will be much brighter. The reorientation
- of East European trade away from the Soviet Union, though
- painful in the short term, will work to the long-term advantage
- of Eastern Europe. Having been forced to reduce their reliance
- on Soviet energy and markets, the East European economies will
- emerge more capable of trading with the West. In 1990 and 1991,
- trade between Eastern Europe and members of the European
- Community (EC) expanded significantly, as a number of East
- European firms adjusted surprisingly well to competition on the
- world market. Moreover, the increase would have been larger
- without the barriers that the EC still has in place against such
- products as textiles, steel and agricultural goods. The growth
- of trade with the EC, though not as substantial as the East
- European governments had desired and not enough to offset the
- losses in trade with former COMECON partners, provided some hope
- that Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland might be ready to join
- the EC within the next decade.
- </p>
- <p>Private Property
- </p>
- <p>The fundamental pillar of any capitalist system is the private
- ownership of property. If communism achieved anything in Eastern
- Europe, it was the abolition of private property rights as state
- bureaucracies assumed control of all land and production
- facilities. Thus, one of the most urgent tasks confronting the
- postcommunist governments has been the legalization of private
- ownership and the transfer of state property to private hands.
- Although small-scale privatization has been underway for some
- time throughout Eastern Europe and programs for large-scale
- privatization have been adopted in Czechoslovakia, Hungary,
- Poland, and even Romania, a number of thorny problems regarding
- fairness, speed, and efficiency have arisen.
- </p>
- <p> The controversy surrounding restitution or compensation for
- citizens whose property was expropriated by the communist
- regimes complicates the whole question of privatization. The
- value of affected property in Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and
- Poland has been estimated at more than $22 billion. Because the
- notion of shifting ownership to private hands is predicated on
- the assumption that the state owns the property to be
- transferred, ambiguity about the state's claim poses obvious
- difficulties for privatization. Potential buyers of state
- assets will be reluctant to purchase anything that might later
- be subject to restitution claims. Moreover, the lengthy process
- needed to verify potential claims could delay privatization
- indefinitely, thereby thwarting hopes of swift ownership
- transfer.
- </p>
- <p> The restitution issue roused heated debate both inside and
- outside the East European governments and became a factor in
- local and national elections. In Hungary, one of the contending
- parties, the independent Small-holders, made the demand for
- restitution of farmland its main electorial plank. Ultimately,
- the East European governments tried to reach compromises that
- would be deemed fair by the public, yet would minimally affect
- plans for privatization. In Poland, a compromise bill limited
- restitution in kind to property seized in violation of the laws
- existing at the time of seizure. Vouchers that could be used to
- purchase shares in privatized firms would be granted to all
- other successful claimants. Hungary provided for compensation
- in the form of property bonds that could be used in land
- auctions or exchanged for shares in privatized companies. Only
- Czechoslovakia permitted restitution in kind on a wider scale,
- and even there dispossessed owners had to fulfill strict
- conditions and file claims within a limited time. Thus, although
- lingering pressure for expanded restitution remained an obstacle
- to privatization, the acute uncertainly that arose in 1990 and
- early 1991 had largely subsided by the end of 1991.
- </p>
- <p> Other formidable obstacles to privatization remained,
- however. During the first two years of their economic
- transitions, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland took widely
- differing approaches to privatization. Hungary adopted the most
- cautious approach, eschewing plans involving either a mass
- giveaway of state-owned companies through vouchers or the broad
- transfer of ownership to workers and managers. Instead,
- Hungarian officials sought to privatize on a case-by-case basis
- using traditional sales methods. That approach had the virtue of
- simplicity, but the results it produced in 1990 and 1991 were
- not especially encouraging: The sales of just one of the most
- successful Hungarian companies took many months longer than
- expected. By mid-1991, some Hungarian officials, including
- Finance Minister Mihaly Kupa, openly complained that
- privatization would take several decades or even centuries if
- the government relied exclusively on selling off companies one
- at a time.
- </p>
- <p> Case-by-case privatization faced the same difficulties in
- Czechoslovakia and Poland. Unlike Hungary, however,
- Czechoslovakia and Poland responded by devising mass giveaway
- schemes that they hoped would expedite the privatization
- process. The Polish plan called for the establishment of 12
- investment management funds, headed by Western financial
- consultants, that would control 60 percent of the shares of
- Poland's several hundred largest companies. The state treasury
- and the company's employees would divide the remaining 40
- percent of shares in each company. The investment funds were to
- start trading shares in the companies immediately after the
- initial allocation in 1992. At the same time, an equal number of
- shares from each investment fund were to be distributed free of
- charge to all 28 million Polish adults, who would be entitled
- to trade shares in the funds starting in mid-1993.
- </p>
- <p> The Czechoslovak government came up with a more elaborate
- approach, which called for 3,000 large state-owned companies to
- be sold off by means of "coupon privatization." All companies
- selected for the program had to submit a privatization plan by
- November 1991 and, except for a few firms of particular
- national importance, were entitled to sell shares to any
- interested buyers, including foreigners. The large majority of
- companies, which were unable to sell enough of their shares by
- standard methods, were then channeled into the "coupon
- privatization" scheme. Under the scheme, shares in enterprises
- were to be auctioned off in two waves to holders of investment
- vouchers, which were available to all adult citizens of
- Czechoslovakia for a nominal price of 1,035 crowns (roughly
- $35). Initial estimates suggested that some three to four
- million people--approximately one-third of the adult
- population--would purchase vouchers; the actual number of
- buyers in 1991 amounted to only about 450,000. A last-minute
- rush of purchases in January 1992, however, brought the total
- up to the initial projections.
- </p>
- <p> Western governments should provide large-scale aid, $5
- billion to $10 billion a year, specifically targeted for
- infrastructure development and environmental cleanup.
- </p>
- <p> Neither the Polish nor the Czechoslovak plan has turned out
- to be entirely feasible and both are potentially susceptible to
- abuse. The Czechoslovak proposal has been criticized for
- failing to introduce the new capital and management expertise
- that is needed to revive ailing industries and stem the growing
- obsolescence of the industrial base. If most of the newly
- privatized companies quickly go bankrupt, the experience could
- permanently set back the cause of mass privatization in
- Czechoslovakia and elsewhere. Quite apart from that problem,
- the Czechoslovaki approach is prone to dangers from insider
- trading and fraud. Because most Czechoslovak citizens lack the
- information required to make sound investment decisions, the
- most valuable shares may end up going to voucher holders with
- access to inside information. This drawback could be mitigated
- somewhat if workers and managers used their vouchers to buy
- shares in their own firms, but the potential for abuse cannot be
- elminated altogether. Finally, the plan has been attacked by
- both Czech and Slovak politicians for endangering the interests
- of their respective republics by enabling foreign investment
- funds to make quick profits from undervalued companies. So
- bitter did their complaints become by the fall of 1991 that they
- delayed the implementation of the entire program, much to the
- dismay of the federal government.
- </p>
- <p> Although the Polish plan avoids most of the Czechoslovak
- proposal's shortcomings, it is dependent on the governments
- ability to recruit a sufficient number of Western fund managers
- who can adjust to doing business in Poland, itself a daunting
- task. Further, the long-term financial underpinnings of the
- program, including compensation to fund management and operation
- of the stock market, have never been fully clarified. Nor has
- there been any concrete vision of the investment funds' role
- over the longer term: whether they will be preserved,
- liquidated, or broken up. The concept of distributing
- investment shares to every Polish adult has also come under
- attack from legislators who believe this approach is too slow
- and financially unpredictable. Because of these problems, the
- scope of the plan was scaled back substantially in October 1991,
- when 171 of the proposed 400 enterprises were dropped from the
- first round of the distribution scheme, including some of the
- largest Polish companies. Later on, other companies were
- excluded because of antitrust concerns, raising further doubts
- about the plan.
- </p>
- <p> The slow pace of case-by-case privatization in Hungary, and
- the problems connected with the Czechoslovak and Polish
- versions of mass privatization prompted some East European
- officials to reconsider the idea of condoning spontaneous
- privatization--the transfer of ownership to workers and
- managers--at least for small-and medium-sized firms.
- Initially, the East Europeans governments were reluctant to
- promote spontaneous privatization because of a widespread and
- accurate perception that it had been exploited by ex-communist
- party officials to retain influence in society through the
- ownership of fraudulently acquired property. To preclude a
- recurrence of such abuses, East European advocates of
- spontaneous privatization, such as Hungary's Kupa, proposed new
- legal safeguards ensuring that workers as well as managers would
- benefit from the process. Although supporters of spontaneous
- privatization had gained considerable ground by the start of
- 1992 in Hungary and Poland, the debate regarding privatization
- may not be fully settled for years to come.
- </p>
- <p> Even in the unlikely event that all the shortcomings in the
- privatization schemes could be worked out, private property
- rights would remain ambiguous. Over the last few years, the
- East European countries have created new forms of property that
- cannot be neatly classified as either state-owned or private.
- Early reforms to decentralize economic decision-making without
- actually privatizing firms led to the emergence of enterprises
- governed by workers' councils or by a combination of workers
- and managers who had not been given formal title to the
- property. In both cases the state still nominally owned the
- companies, but those who actually ran them were accountable only
- to themselves and behaved accordingly. Eventually, these
- nebulous companies may be transformed into commercial
- enterprises governed by boards of directors, which can then be
- either retained by the state or privatized. Until clarification
- occurs across the board, enterprises existing in the limbo
- between state and private ownership will severely impede East
- European economic performance.
- </p>
- <p>Worker Resistance
- </p>
- <p> Until 1989, blue-collar workers in all East European
- countries lived under broadly similar political and labor
- conditions. For the most part, they were allowed only ritual
- participation in national politics, and were strictly limited in
- their participation in the workplace and at the local level. In
- return for their political and labor quiescence, most workers
- received certain economic benefits from the state, including job
- security, stable and subsidized prices, and a lax work regime
- with low performance standards. Recent advances toward a
- free-market orientation introduced blue-collar workers to
- heightened performance pressures, job insecurity, and income
- disparities. At the same time, workers began, openly and
- legally, to articulate demands, organize independent unions, and
- exert political influence. The convergence of these two
- developments--economic hardships coupled with much greater
- political freedom--spurred workers in Eastern Europe to join
- in opposing some of the harshest austerity measures.
- </p>
- <p> The degree of worker resistance to shock therapy programs has
- varied from country to country, but in every case some of the
- strongest opposition has come from workers whose job security
- and living standards have been threatened. In Czechoslovakia,
- for example, the threat of widespread labor unrest in early 1991
- forced the federal government to back away from its plan to
- quadruple the prices of electricity, gasoline, and heating.
- Similarly, protests by workers in Slovakia, who feared losing
- their jobs, helped induce the government to refrain from closing
- down inefficient factories in the Slovak Republic. After
- initially promising to halt all arms transfers to the Third
- World, Czechoslovak officials gave in to worker pressure and
- permitted Slovak factories to continue producing tanks,
- air-defence missiles, training aircraft, and related equipment
- for export to Iran, Syria, and other countries. Although
- Czechoslovakia suspended all weapons sales to the Middle East
- in October 1991 to facilitate the Arab-Israeli peace
- negotiations, growing pressure from Slovak industrial workers
- later compelled the federal government to allow the sales to go
- forward and seek potential arms customers elsewhere.
- </p>
- <p> Even after the Czechoslovak government took steps to
- preserve jobs in the military industries, however, labor unrest
- in Slovakia persisted. Three hundred and eighty thousand
- metalworkers staged a one hour warning strike in Bratislava in
- November 1991 to protest higher prices and the decline in living
- standards. Similar protests occurred in other industries in
- Slovakia. The federal government also found itself under attack
- from workers on collective farms in both Slovakia and the Czech
- lands, who feared unemployment if plans for the privatization
- of agriculture went ahead. The unexpected resistance crippled
- efforts to decollectivize agriculture in 1990 and 1991. By the
- start of 1992, worker unrest in Czechoslovakia had proven to be
- a key impediment to all types of economic reform, especially the
- federal government's plans for large-scale privatization.
- </p>
- <p> In Poland, too, the first threats to the shock therapy
- program that then prime minister Tadeusz Mazowiecki's
- noncommunist-led government implemented in January 1990 came
- from miners, shipbuilders, and other workers who were concerned
- about unemployment. Mazowiecki's program enjoyed unusually
- strong popular support for several months and produced dramatic
- results, but by the late summer of 1990, public approval had
- ebbed and labor protests had begun. These growing signs of
- discontent induced the government to slow down plans for
- privatization and afforded Lech Walesa an opportunity to seek
- the Polish presidency. The presidential elections of late 1990
- ended in a decisive rebuff for Mazowiecki and an equally
- decisive victory for Walesa, confirming the extent of popular
- dissatisfaction with the austerity program.
- </p>
- <p> Once Walesa had taken office, however, unrest among workers
- continued to grow, as the basic framework of the shock therapy
- policies remained in place and the main architect of those
- policies, Finance Minister Leszak Balcerowicz, retained his
- post. Workers demanded that large factories be kept open and
- that wage restraint be eliminated or at least eased. On the
- former point, the government had made significant concessions
- by the fall of 1991. The inconclusive results and low turnout
- in the parliamentary elections of October 1991, the substantial
- protest vote that went to the former Communist party, the two
- months of wrangling before a less reform-minded government
- emerged under Jan Olszewski, and the proliferation of strikes
- across Poland all suggested that resistance among workers to
- shock therapy would hinder attempts to proceed further with
- radical reforms in Poland.
- </p>
- <p> In Hungary as well, labor unrest caused extensive disruption
- and generated pressure on the government to relax its austerity
- program. In October 1990, a cab drivers' strike brought Budapest
- to a virtual standstill for several days, dramatically
- illustrating the growing public discontent. A few months later,
- the threat of mass protests by workers at the huge Ikarus bus
- manufacturing plant influenced the decision of Hungarian leaders
- to seek outside investment to keep the ailing factory in
- business. During the summer of 1991, the Hungarian government
- abandoned its plans to cut agricultural subsidies after farm
- workers organized large rallies nationwide to protest grain
- surpluses and call for higher grain prices.
- </p>
- <p> Workers in other East European countries protested austerity
- measures as well. In September 1991 thousands of coal miners
- from the Jiu Valley in western Romania stormed into Bucharest
- seeking higher wages, lower prices, and the government's
- resignation. Ensuing clashes with the police and security
- forces left three people dead and dozens injured. In Bulgaria,
- labor protests did not erupt into mass violence in 1990 or 1991,
- but strikes and work stoppages helped bring down the communist-
- dominated government in November 1990 and impeded the economic
- reforms of the new, noncommunist government. For example, a
- strike by 27,000 Bulgarian coal miners in August 1991 led to
- significant wage increases, contravening the government's anti-
- inflationary policies. Subsequent waves of strikes, including
- one by more than 4,000 workers at the Arsenal weapons factory in
- December 1991, brought additional pressure to bear on the
- government.
- </p>
- <p> Workers in Eastern Europe have good reason to be leery of
- drastic economic reform. The experience of eastern Germany
- demonstrated that the sacrifices required during the transition
- from a state-controlled economy to a free-market system fell
- disproportionately on blue-collar workers. Unemployment in
- eastern Germany soared to 30 percent in 1991, and the rate
- would have been even higher if underemployment and part-time
- work were taken into account. Without the advantages that
- reunification brought to eastern Germany, the sacrifices that
- will be required in the other East European countries may make
- the situation in the former GDR seem pleasant by comparison.
- </p>
- <p> The extent to which worker resistance becomes a crippling
- obstacle to reform will depend, in part, on the precautionary
- measures to cushion shock therapy. The Hungarian government has
- sought to soften the impact of rising unemployment, which
- reached 6.1 percent on September 1991, by providing generous
- unemployment benefits of up to three times the minimum wage for
- as long as two years. Similarly, Romanian officials have tried
- to head off labor unrest by preserving housing subsidies and a
- few other price supports. Although these policies have obvious
- drawbacks, they are indicative of the trade-offs that may be
- required to ensure worker support for--or at least
- acquiescence to--radical economic measures. Although
- precautions of this sort will insulate the East European
- governments to some degree, the success of economic reform in
- Eastern Europe will ultimately depend on the readiness of
- workers to put up with austerity--perhaps severe austerity--over the short to medium term in return for much greater
- political freedom and the hope of evential prosperity.
- </p>
- <p>Sequencing Reforms
- </p>
- <p> The ideal shock therapy program would pursue the full range
- of reforms--macro-economic stabilization, price
- liberalization, currency convertibility, trade and banking
- reform, labor deregulation, broad privatization, and
- appropriate legal and social measures--simultaneously. For
- both political and economic reasons, however, a truly
- comprehensive package has been impossible except in the very
- special case of eastern Germany. The other East European
- governments have found it necessary to choose among certain
- steps rather than pursue all avenues at once. Unfortunately,
- some measures have little or no effect unless combined with
- other measures, and it is often difficult to evaluate a sequence
- of reforms before implementation. Further, if the austerity
- required during the early stages of a shock therapy program
- generates enough popular opposition and discord among elites,
- it will complicate the subsequent enactment of any deferred
- reforms.
- </p>
- <p> This problem has been evident in Poland, the first East
- European country to undertake shock therapy. Enacted in January
- 1990, the Polish program removed controls on prices, countered
- inflation through wage restraints, restricted the money supply,
- reduced trade barriers, and devalued the zloty to make the
- currency convertible. Although the program envisioned large-
- scale privatization, it deferred that goal pending the success
- of the initial reforms. From a political standpoint, the delay
- in implementing privatization may have been necessary; and
- economically, freeing prices would help in deciding which
- companies were worth trying to sell to private buyers. However,
- the decline in Polish living standards during the first two
- years of shock therapy has made the public wary of future
- reforms, including plans for privatization.
- </p>
- <p> Looking back in late 1991, Polish Minister of Privatization
- Janusz Lewandowski publicly regretted the sequence of reforms
- that his government has chosen. In an interview with the Moscow
- weekly Novoe Vremya, he said:
- </p>
- <p> "So risky a measure as the freeing of prices should have been
- carried out simultaneously with the greatest possible
- introduction of private enterprise and large-scale
- privatization. We made that mistake here. At first we freed
- prices and strengthened the zloty, and only a year later got
- down to privatization. Instead, we should have done the two
- simultaneously, or better yet, privatization should have come
- ahead of the decontrol of price formation. Then the
- hyperinflation could have been overcome earlier and without such
- a shock."
- </p>
- <p> Lewandowski's comments illustrate the difficulty of
- formulating an economically viable sequence of reforms that
- will also be politically acceptable. The approach that the
- Polish government took in 1990 and 1991 has made it
- inordinately difficult for any future government to close down
- inefficient factories. Efforts to privatize firms that might be
- efficient if they were to reduce their labor force have been
- similarly hindered. For example, during the October 1991
- electorial campaign, Prime Minister Jan Bielecki's government
- found it necessary to bail out the giant Ursus tractor plant and
- a number of ailing military factories. The uncertainty that has
- followed the October 1991 elections will further complicate
- efforts at privatization in Poland.
- </p>
- <p> Polish officials face obstacles that are typical of those
- bedeviling all the East European countries. In 1990 and most of
- 1991, officials in Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland
- concentrated primarily on dealing with the easiest problems
- first--macroeconomic stabilization and the control of
- inflation. They were less inclined to call for measures that
- would bring about large-scale unemployment. The experience of
- the former GDR, where industrial output fell by 50 percent and
- unemployment rose to 30 percent in the first year after
- reunification, reinforced the cautious inclinations of
- governments elsewhere in Eastern Europe. Although the painfully
- compressed transition in eastern Germany created the basis for
- a near-term recovery, the other East European countries could
- not endure a similar course because they lack the protection
- that the former GDR received. Since these governments have to
- proceed more gradually, the way they handle three sets of
- reforms will be critical to the success of their shock therapy
- designs:
- </p>
- <p>Currency Convertibility
- </p>
- <p> Currency convertibility and trade liberalization can be
- invaluable in the earliest stages of a reform program. If prices
- in Poland had been freed without a convertible currency and a
- lowering of trade barriers, the high degree of monopoly in
- Polish industry might have thwarted the development of a
- meaningful pricing system. By allowing foreign competition, the
- Polish program ensured that prices, once freed, would become
- true market prices. However, foreign competition could swiftly
- render domestic industries obsolete, denying them the
- opportunity to become internationally competitive. Even if
- allowing the unprofitable majority of companies to go bankrupt
- makes economic sense, the experience in eastern Germany
- demonstrates that the unemployment resulting from widespread
- de-industrialization carries severe political costs. A string
- of violent protests against rising unemployment and other
- hardships could undermine the East European governments' ability
- to sustain their shock therapy programs.
- </p>
- <p>Financial Restructuring
- </p>
- <p> Without an elaborate system of commercial banks and stock
- markets the allocation of capital to East European industries,
- whether privatized or state-owned, is likely to remain skewed.
- Establishing a viable financial system, especially private
- banks, should therefore be one of the highest priorities for the
- East European governments. Nevertheless, the Polish experience
- suggests that the task is much harder than one might expect.
- Because almost all the loans by banks are to firms that have not
- yet been privatized, there are problems in determining whether
- existing banks can be run efficiently. In addition, the banking
- scandal that came to light in Poland in mid-1991 is but one
- illustration of the serious risks of abuse and corruption that
- plague the newly formed systems. That experience prompted the
- chief inspector for Poland's National Bank to warn that "the
- establishment of a safe banking system" would be "extremely
- costly" and could take more than a decade.
- </p>
- <p>Privatization
- </p>
- <p> The longer the task of privatization is delayed, the harder
- it becomes to implement. The East European states thus have an
- incentive to proceed rapidly in privatizing companies. The
- Polish experience reveals some of the dangers in putting off
- privatization. Nevertheless, the obstacles to privatization
- evident throughout Eastern Europe provide little reason to doubt
- economist Josef Brada's prediction in a 1991 essay that
- </p>
- <p> "for a rather indefinite future [the East European] countries
- will have economies where large industrial units partly or
- wholly owned by the state will co-exist with or indeed,
- predominate over, large privatized firms in the hands of
- residents or foreigners and small industrial units that will
- arise as the result of the efforts of indigenous entrepreneurs."
- </p>
- <p> But if this prediction is indeed borne out (that is, if
- large-scale privatization does take a very long time to
- accomplish), the whole future of postcommunist economic reforms
- will be endangered. The Hungarian economist Janos Kornai has
- argued that the impossibility of privatizing in a "big bang"
- will mean that "for a long time, inevitably, a large part of
- [every East European] economy, in particular the gradually
- shrinking, but still rather large state-owned sector, will run
- inefficiently," dragging down the private sector with it.
- </p>
- <p> There is no universally applicable way that these three types
- of reforms (or others) should be implemented. Because Hungary
- has not experienced the acute crisis that Poland did in late
- 1989, officials in Budapest have been able to proceed more
- gradually in all three areas. Hungarian proponents of shock
- therapy argue, however, that the gradualist approach may be
- safer in the short term, but it will prove more costly over the
- long term once drastic measures are required. Czechoslovakia,
- for its part, has come closer to adopting Polish-style shock
- therapy reforms, thanks largely to the tenacity of the finance
- minister, Vaclav Klaus. But the Czechoslovak reforms have not
- been as sweeping as those in Poland, nor have they fared any
- better with the issue of privatization.
- </p>
- <p> Questions of sequencing also have begun to arise in Bulgaria
- and Romania, both of which were initially slow to undertake
- economic reforms. Since mid-1991, the two countries,
- particularly Bulgaria, have shown signs of eventually moving
- toward some version of shock therapy, which could prove even
- more complicated than analogous programs elsewhere. For
- example, neither Bulgaria nor Romania has much of an industrial
- base; hence, they may be far less willing than Poland was to
- proceed immediately with currency convertability and trade
- liberalization, for fear that their capital stock will be
- undermined by a flood of imports. (In the Polish case, this
- problem was forestalled by the huge devaluation of the zloty.)
- In any event, whatever the precise sequence of reforms that
- individual East European countries arrange, there is bound to be
- a good deal of trial and error, with many adjustments along the
- way.
- </p>
- <p> The sacrifices required during the transition from a state-
- controlled to a free-market system fall disproportionately
- on blue-collar workers.
- </p>
- <p> The west will play a crucial role in the economic
- transformation of Eastern Europe, but the exact nature of this
- role will depend in the actions of the East European states
- themselves, Ultimately, successful reform will have to come from
- within. If the East European countries cannot endure the painful
- steps required to bring about genuine prosperity, no amount of
- Western assistance will help. In fact, Western aid--financial
- or otherwise--would be counterproductive if used by the
- recipients as an excuse to avoid or defer meaningful reforms.
- </p>
- <p> So far, however, the Bulgarian, Czechoslovak, Hungarian, and
- Polish governments have embraced the very measures long urged by
- Western officials and economists. Unlike the former Soviet
- republics, the East European states have moved far more boldly
- down the path of reform then most observers had expected. Yet,
- ironically, almost all the recent debate about Western financial
- and technical aid has focused on what can be done for the former
- Soviet government and the republics, overshadowing the amounts
- that have been used more efficiently by the East European
- countries. Memories of the dramatic events of 1989 have faded,
- and there emerges the possibility that Eastern Europe will once
- again become a forgotten region for the West.
- </p>
- <p> This loss of interest in Eastern Europe is unfortunate and
- dangerous. Facilitating successful reform in Eastern Europe is
- vital not only because economic collapse could spur floods of
- refugees and violent civil disorder, but also because a failed
- transition in Eastern Europe would discredit the move from
- socialism to capitalism. This would play in the hands of anti-
- reformist elements in the former Soviet republics and would set
- back the cause of free markets and democracy all across Europe.
- </p>
- <p> To be sure, severe budgetary constraints in the West will
- limit the direct contribution the United States and its allies
- can make to the economic development of Eastern Europe. The
- German government's experience in meeting the costs of
- reunification illustrates the problems that will arise in other
- cases as reforms progress. Even with these constraints, however,
- relatively modest increases in technical and economical
- assistance, if properly targeted, could prove decisive.
- </p>
- <p> No step would be more welcome for the East European
- countries than the elimination of EC and U.S. trade barriers,
- particularly for agricultural products, textiles, and steel. The
- East European states can successfully compete with Western
- producers in these three industries, but they have been barred
- from entering prospective markets. Projections by the Overseas
- Development Council suggest that East European exports of
- textiles and apparel to the West could increase nearly four-fold
- if trade barriers were removed. Exports of steel and
- agricultural products could also rise far beyond current
- levels. Although there will be strong political resistance in
- Western Europe to the easing, or elimination of trade barriers,
- the United States should emphasize the incongruity of the EC's
- urging the enactment of free-market reforms in Eastern Europe
- while adopting policies that greatly impede those reforms. The
- United States should also be willing to dismantle all or most of
- its own remaining barriers to East European trade without
- demanding immediate reciprocity from the East European
- countries, as was done with Czechoslovakia in October 1991.
- </p>
- <p> Access to foreign private investment will also be vital for
- the East European countries during their economic transitions,
- but relatively little investment has flowed into the region so
- far. Only about $2.5 billion actually arrived between late 1989
- and mid-1991, and that money was distributed very unevenly, with
- roughly 60 percent of the total invested in Hungary.
- Accelerating privatization in all the East European countries
- will require much larger sums, perhaps $20 billion or more. Of
- course, the amount of private investment in Eastern Europe will
- depend in the long term on the prospects for profit. Those
- prospects, in turn, will grow only if political stability is
- ensured and economic conditions begin to improve, criteria that
- may not be fully met for at least several years if at all.
- </p>
- <p> In the meantime, however, Western governments and non-
- governmental organizations can foster a propitious climate for
- foreign investment. The "association" agreements that several
- East European countries recently concluded with the EC will
- help boost investor confidence, but that status would be far
- more valuable if combined with the elimination of trade
- barriers. The increased use of export credit guarantees from
- Western governments and international financial organizations
- would also help create a better investment climate without
- requiring additional direct expenditures. The climates for
- investment can be further improved through the development of
- a suitable business infrastructure in each country. Western
- governments can provide technical support and expertise on
- keeping accurate statistics, running financial and banking
- systems, and monitoring and maintaining adequate environmental
- standards. In this regard, programs like the "twinning" of
- Polish banks with western counterparts, sponsored by the World
- Bank and the International Finance Corporation, will be
- invaluable. So too will the programs that have recently been set
- up to train East European company managers and entrepreneurs at
- Western business schools.
- </p>
- <p> Another key step for Western governments will be to give
- greater emphasis to privatization then to conversion. Starting
- in the early 1950s, the Soviet Union required most of the East
- European countries to maintain large defense industries. Now,
- with communism abandoned and the Warsaw Pact defunct, all of the
- East European states have been seeking to reduce, or at least
- stabilize, their military spending and convert a significant
- portion of their military factories to civilian production.
- Plans for conversion have won support in the West and should
- certainly be encouraged, especially when conversion is
- cost-effective. Successes include the huge Slovakian
- manufacturing complex Zavody Tazkeho Strojarstva (ZTS), which
- received help from German investors in converting some of its
- assembly lines from the production of tanks to tractors,
- bulldozers, earth movers, steam rollers, and dump trucks. If
- the whole of ZTS can be sold off to private investors, it could
- well become one of the largest European producers of civilian
- heavy vehicles. In Hungary, a former military factory known as
- the Gamma Works, which produced equipment for defense against
- chemical and nuclear attacks, has successfully reoriented its
- facilities to produce nuclear medical diagnostic instruments,
- automation systems, and other nonmilitary goods.
- </p>
- <p> Despite these successes, officials in both East and West
- should be aware that plans for conversion do not always make
- much sense. In many cases, factories that produced military
- equipment cannot shift over to civilian production at an
- acceptable cost; or if they do shift over, they have no hope of
- making a profit. It would make more sense for those East
- European governments to shut down those factories. The urgent
- need is to privatize factories, not merely convert them.
- Otherwise, conversion may become a way of preserving subsidies
- to inherently unprofitable firms. Private owners of factories
- have every incentive to convert to civilian production if it
- could make economic sense, they would not have brought the
- factories in the first place. The best way for the West to
- encourage conversion in Eastern Europe--aside from providing
- modest technical advice--is to encourage privatization and
- let the market decide which factories will be viable in
- producing civilian goods.
- </p>
- <p> Debt relief is another urgent priority. Except in Romania,
- and to some extent Czechoslovakia, large foreign debts
- accumulated by the old East European communist regimes have
- impeded economic reforms. It is unwise and unfair to compel the
- fledgling democratic governments to shoulder the burden of
- their predecessors' mistakes. The agreement by the Paris Club
- (the group of 17 major Western governmental creditors) in March
- 1991 to write off half of Poland's government-held debt provided
- a deserved reward to a country that had undertaken drastic
- internal reforms. Other states in the region can benefit from
- similar measures as they embark on their own shock therapy
- programs. Just as important will be the relaxation of
- commercial debts, something that the Paris Club agreement
- required of the Polish government. No doubt, negotiations
- between the East European states and their commercial creditors
- will proceed more slowly than the government-to-government
- talks, but a forthcoming approach by governmental lenders should
- expedite far-reaching reductions in Eastern Europe's commercial
- debts.
- </p>
- <p> Finally, even if Western officials do their best to
- encourage private investment and reduce trade barriers,
- increased governmental assistance to the East European countries
- will be essential. Substantial amounts of aid have already
- channeled through the EC, the European Bank, the International
- Monetary Fund, and the World Bank, but the total falls far
- short of the amounts the East European states will need to
- sustain themselves through the transition. East European leaders
- have acknowledged that unemployment in their countries could
- double, triple, or even quadruple in 1992 and 1993, bringing
- with it the risk of "disorder" and "strike after strike."
- Economic crises could rapidly overwhelm the social "safety-net"
- programs that Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland have set up.
- Increased Western aid will be needed simply to ease the growing
- hardships ahead.
- </p>
- <p> Whatever the political rationale for increased Western aid,
- such aid will not be of long-term benefit unless it is put to
- productive use. Western governments should provide large-scale
- aid, $5 billion to $10 billion a year; specifically targeted
- for infrastructure development and environmental cleanup.
- Roughly one-third of this money would come from the United
- States and would be distributed both bilaterally and via the
- major international lending institutions. The East European
- countries lack modern transportation and communications
- networks, and sorely need to address the disastrous
- environmental degradation that occurred during the communist
- era. Funding from the West for these objectives would improve
- long-term prospects for economic growth in Eastern Europe, and
- would also absorb tens of thousands of workers who would
- otherwise be unemployed.
- </p>
- <p> These policy guidelines alone will not be enough to
- stimulate economic recovery in Eastern Europe, but at least they
- will enable the West to play as constructive a role as possible.
- As Polish prime minister Bielecki emphasized recently, failure
- is not inevitable just because "a miracle cannot happen," and
- the economic transitions may take more than a decade. The road
- ahead in Eastern Europe is long, but the postcommunist states
- are undertaking radical solutions to the daunting problems they
- confront, and that is no small accomplishment.
- </p>
- </body>
- </article>
- </text>
-